Growth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture

Part I of this essay explained the sequence of events that enabled the neoclassical paradigm to regain its dominant position in mainstream economics following serious challenges by ‘Keynesian’ economists. This second essay seeks to answer the question of why the economics profess...

Descripción completa

Guardado en:
Detalles Bibliográficos
Autor principal: Hendrik Van den Berg
Formato: article
Lenguaje:DE
EN
FR
Publicado: Editura ASE Bucuresti 2014
Materias:
Acceso en línea:https://doaj.org/article/35e16036757643dcab8195339595c0a2
Etiquetas: Agregar Etiqueta
Sin Etiquetas, Sea el primero en etiquetar este registro!
id oai:doaj.org-article:35e16036757643dcab8195339595c0a2
record_format dspace
spelling oai:doaj.org-article:35e16036757643dcab8195339595c0a22021-12-02T02:04:41ZGrowth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture1843-22981844-8208https://doaj.org/article/35e16036757643dcab8195339595c0a22014-05-01T00:00:00Z http://jpe.ro/pdf.php?id=6300 https://doaj.org/toc/1843-2298https://doaj.org/toc/1844-8208Part I of this essay explained the sequence of events that enabled the neoclassical paradigm to regain its dominant position in mainstream economics following serious challenges by ‘Keynesian’ economists. This second essay seeks to answer the question of why the economics profession was so willing to sustain the neoclassical paradigm in the face of the reality-based challenges by ‘Keynesian’ economists like Harrod and Domar. The answer is sought in the culture of economics, the history of science in general, and the study of power in the field of political economy. This article draws heavily on the work of the French sociologist Pierre Bourdieu, who divides culture into habitus (procedures and dispositions) and doxa (more abstract beliefs and philosophies), in order to provide insight into how culture affects economic thinking. Bourdieu’s concept of symbolic violence helps to explain how a narrower neoclassical growth model was enthusiastically accepted as a replacement for the ‘Keynesian’ Harrod-Domar growth model. Financial and business interests clearly understood the power of culture and they used their accumulated wealth to support the neoliberal doxa and neoclassical habitus that would induce economists to willingly provide intellectual cover for policies that benefitted those financial and business interests. We conclude with a discussion on how the history of thought on economic development might have evolved if the Keynesian paradigm, and its dynamic Harrod-Domar model, had prevailedHendrik Van den BergEditura ASE BucurestiarticleBourdieuHarrod-Domarsociology of economicsEconomics as a scienceHB71-74DEENFRJournal of Philosophical Economics, Vol VII, Iss 2, Pp 2-26 (2014)
institution DOAJ
collection DOAJ
language DE
EN
FR
topic Bourdieu
Harrod-Domar
sociology of economics
Economics as a science
HB71-74
spellingShingle Bourdieu
Harrod-Domar
sociology of economics
Economics as a science
HB71-74
Hendrik Van den Berg
Growth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture
description Part I of this essay explained the sequence of events that enabled the neoclassical paradigm to regain its dominant position in mainstream economics following serious challenges by ‘Keynesian’ economists. This second essay seeks to answer the question of why the economics profession was so willing to sustain the neoclassical paradigm in the face of the reality-based challenges by ‘Keynesian’ economists like Harrod and Domar. The answer is sought in the culture of economics, the history of science in general, and the study of power in the field of political economy. This article draws heavily on the work of the French sociologist Pierre Bourdieu, who divides culture into habitus (procedures and dispositions) and doxa (more abstract beliefs and philosophies), in order to provide insight into how culture affects economic thinking. Bourdieu’s concept of symbolic violence helps to explain how a narrower neoclassical growth model was enthusiastically accepted as a replacement for the ‘Keynesian’ Harrod-Domar growth model. Financial and business interests clearly understood the power of culture and they used their accumulated wealth to support the neoliberal doxa and neoclassical habitus that would induce economists to willingly provide intellectual cover for policies that benefitted those financial and business interests. We conclude with a discussion on how the history of thought on economic development might have evolved if the Keynesian paradigm, and its dynamic Harrod-Domar model, had prevailed
format article
author Hendrik Van den Berg
author_facet Hendrik Van den Berg
author_sort Hendrik Van den Berg
title Growth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture
title_short Growth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture
title_full Growth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture
title_fullStr Growth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture
title_full_unstemmed Growth theory after Keynes, part II: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture
title_sort growth theory after keynes, part ii: 75 years of obstruction by the mainstream economics culture
publisher Editura ASE Bucuresti
publishDate 2014
url https://doaj.org/article/35e16036757643dcab8195339595c0a2
work_keys_str_mv AT hendrikvandenberg growththeoryafterkeynespartii75yearsofobstructionbythemainstreameconomicsculture
_version_ 1718402701975355392