Advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit

Advocatus populi and advocatus diaboli – on law, arguments and strategies in Brexit negotiations The decision on leaving the EU was driven by identity politics rather than sober economic considerations. The British government will have to reconcile the political expectations of the voters (red...

Descripción completa

Guardado en:
Detalles Bibliográficos
Autores principales: Arkadiusz Radwan, Hans-Bernd Schäfer
Formato: article
Lenguaje:EN
PL
Publicado: Ksiegarnia Akademicka Publishing 2021
Materias:
Law
K
J
Acceso en línea:https://doaj.org/article/c871309361e24d23b6d5f1c2b55ab43d
Etiquetas: Agregar Etiqueta
Sin Etiquetas, Sea el primero en etiquetar este registro!
id oai:doaj.org-article:c871309361e24d23b6d5f1c2b55ab43d
record_format dspace
spelling oai:doaj.org-article:c871309361e24d23b6d5f1c2b55ab43d2021-11-27T13:06:41ZAdvocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit10.12797/Politeja.14.2017.49.141733-67162391-6737https://doaj.org/article/c871309361e24d23b6d5f1c2b55ab43d2021-06-01T00:00:00Zhttps://journals.akademicka.pl/politeja/article/view/1645https://doaj.org/toc/1733-6716https://doaj.org/toc/2391-6737 Advocatus populi and advocatus diaboli – on law, arguments and strategies in Brexit negotiations The decision on leaving the EU was driven by identity politics rather than sober economic considerations. The British government will have to reconcile the political expectations of the voters (red lines) with their long term economic aspirations, as it will be accountable towards the electorate for delivering both. The two-years sunset clause elicits the specter a hard Brexit scenario with the UK ending up as Union’s uncushioned dropout. The failure to work out any withdrawal agreement, ergo UK downgrading to a mere WTO status makes up the BATNA for the negotiating parties. From the day of the notification made pursuant to Article 50 TEU, this BATNA looms larger for the UK than it does for the EU-27, as the costs of losing the access to the other party’s market are estimated to be much higher for London than for Brussels. Avoiding hard Brexit will only be possible if a new model of future EU-UK trade relations will be worked out. The cost calculation for EU-27 cannot be limited to a ‘single game’ (one-stage strife) but it has to take into account the influence of the negotiated outcome on future behaviour of other players to the game, i.e. the remaining MS. Both parties remain in a confrontational logic. They resort to entering a chicken game – a negotiation strategy of signalling a limited room for manoeuvre. The main demands of the Leave camp are now being taken by the British government for red-lines supposed to be limiting London’s array of acceptable negotiation outcomes (Brexit means Brexit). On the other hand, the EU-27, as a heterogeneous group of countries remains inherently unpredictable, which may be also perceived as a structural narrowing of Brussels’ room for manoeuvre. Thus, contrary to the received wisdom, the London’s divide et impera strategy would easy turn counter-effective. A tension that exists between meeting voters’ political expectations on the one side, and safeguarding country’s long-term economic prosperity on the other, makes any possible tradeoff hard to accept. A strategy capable of reconciling these conflicting premises would be for London to strive to prevail in political symbolism while at the same time accept far-going concessions in the real sphere by allowing the EU-UK economic integration to be upheld through UK continued Club’s ‘membership in disguise’. The most probable outcome of the Brexit negotiation will be the adoption of a comprehensive free trade agreement. It is unlikely for the withdrawal agreement and/or for the future EU-UK FTA, alleviating the adversity of Brexit for the British economy, to be concluded without London’s readiness to rendering transfer payments towards the EU, and without UK participation in at least some of the Union’s key policies. Furthermore, UK will need to continue following at least some of the internal market regulations. The inherent downside of this arrangement for the UK will be the reduced influence of London on the Brussels-made laws. The compliance of United Kingdom with the EU legislation will need to be flanked by arrangements designed to guarantee a functioning law enforcement through institutionalized dispute resolutions mechanism (e.g. EU-UK court modelled after the EFTA-court). Arkadiusz RadwanHans-Bernd SchäferKsiegarnia Akademicka PublishingarticleBrexitreferendum europejskienegocjacje ustąpienioweUE‑27art. 50 TUEintegracja europejskaLawKPolitical scienceJENPLPoliteja, Vol 14, Iss 4(49) (2021)
institution DOAJ
collection DOAJ
language EN
PL
topic Brexit
referendum europejskie
negocjacje ustąpieniowe
UE‑27
art. 50 TUE
integracja europejska
Law
K
Political science
J
spellingShingle Brexit
referendum europejskie
negocjacje ustąpieniowe
UE‑27
art. 50 TUE
integracja europejska
Law
K
Political science
J
Arkadiusz Radwan
Hans-Bernd Schäfer
Advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit
description Advocatus populi and advocatus diaboli – on law, arguments and strategies in Brexit negotiations The decision on leaving the EU was driven by identity politics rather than sober economic considerations. The British government will have to reconcile the political expectations of the voters (red lines) with their long term economic aspirations, as it will be accountable towards the electorate for delivering both. The two-years sunset clause elicits the specter a hard Brexit scenario with the UK ending up as Union’s uncushioned dropout. The failure to work out any withdrawal agreement, ergo UK downgrading to a mere WTO status makes up the BATNA for the negotiating parties. From the day of the notification made pursuant to Article 50 TEU, this BATNA looms larger for the UK than it does for the EU-27, as the costs of losing the access to the other party’s market are estimated to be much higher for London than for Brussels. Avoiding hard Brexit will only be possible if a new model of future EU-UK trade relations will be worked out. The cost calculation for EU-27 cannot be limited to a ‘single game’ (one-stage strife) but it has to take into account the influence of the negotiated outcome on future behaviour of other players to the game, i.e. the remaining MS. Both parties remain in a confrontational logic. They resort to entering a chicken game – a negotiation strategy of signalling a limited room for manoeuvre. The main demands of the Leave camp are now being taken by the British government for red-lines supposed to be limiting London’s array of acceptable negotiation outcomes (Brexit means Brexit). On the other hand, the EU-27, as a heterogeneous group of countries remains inherently unpredictable, which may be also perceived as a structural narrowing of Brussels’ room for manoeuvre. Thus, contrary to the received wisdom, the London’s divide et impera strategy would easy turn counter-effective. A tension that exists between meeting voters’ political expectations on the one side, and safeguarding country’s long-term economic prosperity on the other, makes any possible tradeoff hard to accept. A strategy capable of reconciling these conflicting premises would be for London to strive to prevail in political symbolism while at the same time accept far-going concessions in the real sphere by allowing the EU-UK economic integration to be upheld through UK continued Club’s ‘membership in disguise’. The most probable outcome of the Brexit negotiation will be the adoption of a comprehensive free trade agreement. It is unlikely for the withdrawal agreement and/or for the future EU-UK FTA, alleviating the adversity of Brexit for the British economy, to be concluded without London’s readiness to rendering transfer payments towards the EU, and without UK participation in at least some of the Union’s key policies. Furthermore, UK will need to continue following at least some of the internal market regulations. The inherent downside of this arrangement for the UK will be the reduced influence of London on the Brussels-made laws. The compliance of United Kingdom with the EU legislation will need to be flanked by arrangements designed to guarantee a functioning law enforcement through institutionalized dispute resolutions mechanism (e.g. EU-UK court modelled after the EFTA-court).
format article
author Arkadiusz Radwan
Hans-Bernd Schäfer
author_facet Arkadiusz Radwan
Hans-Bernd Schäfer
author_sort Arkadiusz Radwan
title Advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit
title_short Advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit
title_full Advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit
title_fullStr Advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit
title_full_unstemmed Advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących Brexit
title_sort advocatus populi i advocatus diaboli – o prawie, argumentach i strategiach stron negocjujących brexit
publisher Ksiegarnia Akademicka Publishing
publishDate 2021
url https://doaj.org/article/c871309361e24d23b6d5f1c2b55ab43d
work_keys_str_mv AT arkadiuszradwan advocatuspopuliiadvocatusdiabolioprawieargumentachistrategiachstronnegocjujacychbrexit
AT hansberndschafer advocatuspopuliiadvocatusdiabolioprawieargumentachistrategiachstronnegocjujacychbrexit
_version_ 1718408768698449920